Eco-evolutionary public goods shared among neighbors

How can we use mathematical modeling and cellular growth data to understand complex co-evolutionary systems, such as the non-linear public goods game?
Published in Ecology & Evolution
Eco-evolutionary public goods shared among neighbors
Like

Share this post

Choose a social network to share with, or copy the URL to share elsewhere

This is a representation of how your post may appear on social media. The actual post will vary between social networks

Many evolving communities depend on public goods that are contributed by some at a cost, but benefit all. The evolutionary stability of cooperation in the public goods game (PGG) is vulnerable to the tragedy of the commons, or free-rider problem. Work in 2015 demonstrated a non-linear relationship between the number of cooperators and the games’s benefit (to fitness) in a cancer cell line. As a result, cooperators and free-riders can coexist. In many systems it is important to ask when such coexistence is stable, “how groups of individuals form and how they arrive at decisions that ultimately benefit all”, or how microbial communities maintain coexistence.

After the cancer cell line results were published, my colleague Philip Gerlee and I felt that two things were still missing. First, the initial mathematical description qualitatively captured the non-linear nature of the cancer cell-public goods game but described payoffs and fitness rather than births and deaths of cells, potentially dismissing population growth. Second, the data (Fig. 1) was not used explicitly to describe net growth rates, possibly because the fitness function of the evolutionary game could be difficult to parameterize. However, we like the PGG in co-evolving cell populations because it can be more than a heuristic. As a result, one might be able to directly tie empirically observed population dynamics to growth factor dynamics and cell cycle dynamics, which Philip and I had modeled before using in vivo growth data and a PGG in linear form

Figure 1
Figure 1: Growth of public good producers is frequency dependent. Archetti et al, PNAS (2015) showed the changes in frequency of producers (cooperators, C) which co-evolve with free-riders (defectors/free-riders, D), as a function of background serum (x-axis) and initial condition (y-axis).

 Since we knew that interesting PGGs are non-linear, Philip Gerlee, Gregory Kimmel, Joel Brown and I began to look into possible mechanisms that can explain coexistence and multiple stable equilibria in this complex system. It was also important to us to link our model to the data from 2015. We started with the idea that the non-linear public good acts in a finite neighborhood, and that its growth rate function steeply increases at first but saturates with a sufficient number of cooperators. We modeled the population game either as a deterministic system, or as a stochastic process, which means that we can predict the number of evolutionary stable states in large populations (deterministic), or the probability of cooperation-extinction in small populations (stochastic). The neighborhood critically determines these states and probabilities (Fig. 2), and the system could explain the previously measured cell line growth rates (we are grateful that Dr Marco Archetti shared the original data with us).

Figure 2
Figure 2: Complex outcomes of the non-linear public goods game. A: Deterministic predictions in which the neighborhood size determines how many equilibria exist and which are stable. If we let the neighborhood size n vary continuously, it controls a saddle-node bifurcation. B: Outcomes of the stochastic version of the model. Small n benefits cooperators (C), large n benefits free-riders (D). In between, coexistence can be observed with high probability.

We are convinced that our approach is relevant to many different systems in ecology and evolution. Thus, we first sent the manuscript to Nature Ecology and Evolution, where it was desk rejected and transferred to Nature Communications. There, it was editorially reviewed, rejected because of research parasitism (we indeed used previously published, i.e. 'old', data), and forwarded to Communications Biology, where we experienced a very constructive peer review process that helped to improve our methods and solidify our results. The referees’ comments triggered us to think deeper about of how the public good’s neighborhood size emerges statistically and how to calculate growth rate functions. 


We are particularly excited about future work in which neighborhood size itself is under selection, hence asking whether and how populations evolve traits that determine the number of peers with which they can interact, and how this impacts the population's ability to adapt.

Please sign in or register for FREE

If you are a registered user on Research Communities by Springer Nature, please sign in

Follow the Topic

Ecology
Life Sciences > Biological Sciences > Ecology

Related Collections

With collections, you can get published faster and increase your visibility.

Cancer epigenetics

With this cross-journal Collection, the editors at Nature Communications, Communications Biology, Communications Medicine, and Scientific Reports invite submissions covering the breadth of research carried out in the field of cancer epigenetics. We will highlight studies aiming at the improvement of our understanding of the epigenetic mechanisms underlying cancer initiation, progression, response to therapy, metastasis and tumour plasticity as well as findings that have the potential to be translated into the clinic.

Publishing Model: Open Access

Deadline: Jan 31, 2025

Neurological disorders as a window into cognitive function

This cross-journal Collection shines a spotlight on research exploring neural mechanisms underlying cognitive functions in people affected by neurological conditions.

Publishing Model: Open Access

Deadline: Jan 31, 2025